Header Ads

Header ADS

IMPERIALISM - Competition in the global market.

Financial Capital, Imperialism and War
From Alexandr Koh, Financial Capital 1927

The economic life of every highly developed capitalist country is now covered by a single financial-capitalist organization. If every country were autarky [i.e. independently without the help of other countries, satisfies its needs] if it were isolated and not bound, the monopoly of capitalist organizations on national markets would be absolute. Competition and even exchange relations with all their attributes: prices, value, etc. would be completely ousted from modern society. The modern economy would cease to be capitalist and would turn into an organized blast society (Polobie of the slave-owning economy).

However, international relations are powerfully and rapidly developing from year to year. Increasingly large masses of goods rush from one country to another, giving rise to and developing into an international whole. Increasingly large masses of capital and labor force are migrating from one end of the world to another, strengthening and expanding international ties.

At present, there is not a single country in the world that could exist in isolation for a more or less long time. The experience of the last imperialist war, as well as the experience of the blockade of Soviet Russia, clearly confirmed this fact.

The modern economy, in its essence, is the economy of the world. Therefore, the extension of the power of financial-capitalist associations to entire countries does not eliminate competition from the system of modern capitalism. Quite the contrary.

As the power of individual capitalist organizations grows stronger, as their influence expands, competition in the world market becomes more and more fierce and destructive.

It must not be forgotten that each of the competing parties is now relying on the resources of entire countries and, moreover, acts hand in hand with powerful state organizations.

On the world market, as well as on national markets, the struggle between powerful capitalist trusts and concerns is waged along three main lines:

1) the struggle for markets,

2) struggle for raw material markets,

3) the struggle for capital investment markets.

All these three types of competition are closely connected with each other and represent, in fact, the three sides of the single capitalist competition. All these three types of competition, when transferred to the world market, lead to the transformation of “peaceful” competition into armed competition, lead to the birth of imperialism as an inevitable policy of modern states.

Fight for markets.

There is an economic law that has long turned into a proverb, and is known to people, even completely unfamiliar with political economy: "demand causes supply." This short proverb contains, if you understand it well, a very large content. It indicates that with the modern development of technology, the production of any product can be brought to any size.

There would be demand, but you can always produce a product and in any quantity. Capitalist production knows no technical obstacles in its path. If it meets certain limits in each period, then these limits are set not by the technical impossibility of further expanding production, but by its economic unprofitability.

The goal of capitalist production is profit.

The capitalist constantly strives to increase the rate of profit. The first means of raising it is to improve the technique of the enterprise and increase the scale of production. At the improvement of the technology of the enterprise at full load, it gives a reduction in production costs, and at constant prices for the product, and an increase in the rate of profit. However, the prices of a product cannot remain unchanged in the domestic market if all entrepreneurs throw more products into the "national" market than before.

Therefore, the capitalists have to transport their surplus products abroad, to those countries where they can be sold for more favorable price. Thus, export abroad is generated not by an absolute overflow of the national market, but by a relative overflow. Surplus products can also be sold domestically; however, such a sale would lower prices, which the capitalists fear so much.

Where are the "surplus" goods from the highly developed capitalist countries going? The answer is self-evident—to countries less developed capitalistically, to countries where industry is not as highly developed and, as a result, prices are high.

However, “surplus goods are thrown away simultaneously from a number of capitalist countries. Every year the mass of commodities seeking external sales is rapidly growing, every year a "free market" is already becoming. Prices in the new markets are becoming more and more equal to the prices of the capitalist countries, and there are fewer and fewer places where goods can be exported at a higher price.

Each of the competitors, therefore, seeks to oust all its rivals from the world market in order to remain alone in the market. The price fight is on fire. Each of the rivals lowers prices in the expectation that the enemy will not stand it, go bankrupt and make room. The winner will be the one who can withstand low prices longer, who can sell goods on the world market for a longer time without profit.

Fierce competition for sales markets, a sharp struggle for the buyer and the price reduction resulting from this struggle in the old days always stimulated the improvement of technology.

In a modern monopoly society, on the other hand, where each of the competitors acts side by side with a powerful state apparatus and uses this apparatus as a weapon in the competitive struggle, the incentives for the improvement of technology are gradually dying out.

In this era, a completely new opportunity opens up for the entrepreneur to withstand the fierce struggle of prices without resorting to the improvement of production methods. This opportunity is created due to the spread of the system of offensive duties.

The system of customs duties existed in capitalist society even before the development of financial-capitalist relations. However, these were, as a rule, protective duties, the fundamental difference between which and modern ones is very great.

The purpose of the protective duty is to secure to the national industry such prices for goods as would provide the average entrepreneur with the recovery of production costs and the usual profit.

The purpose of the offensive tax is to raise domestic prices to the maximum and secure monopolistic super profits for monopoly associations.

Under conditions of free competition in the internal market, any duty, no matter how high it may be, turns into a protective duty since the struggle between domestic entrepreneurs and the transfer of capital into the most profitable industries always reduce the prices of each product to the level of the average production costs plus the average (national) rate of return.

We are saying here that monopolistic organizations inflate prices in the domestic market to the maximum limit.

It would seem that, under the condition of complete dominance in the market, capitalist organizations can raise prices indefinitely. In fact, this is not so.

 The profit of the capitalist depends not only on the height of the price, but also on the quantity of goods sold.

Meanwhile, any increase in the price of a commodity makes this commodity unavailable to more and more consumers and thereby reduces the demand for this commodity.

If the monopoly organization were to raise prices exorbitantly, it would increase its profit per unit of commodity, but at the same time it would be able to sell so little of the commodity that its gross profit would be reduced.

Assume that the cost of producing 1 pair of shoes is 8 rubles. The price of shoes fluctuates. In the same way, the demand for shoes fluctuates, depending on the price.

(…)

We see that the monopoly organization receives the maximum gross profit not at a maximum price of 25 rubles, but at a price of 17 rubles, which, while not being the maximum, still greatly exceeds production costs. It is at this level that the monopoly price is established.

It is necessary to note, however, one more feature. While in a pure capitalist economy the price of industrial products is determined by the average cost of production, the monopoly organizations inflate prices to such a level that it compensates for the cost of production and some profit even for the most basic of enterprises belonging to the association.

Here the price is thus determined by the cost of production, not under average conditions, but under worse conditions. As a result, more advanced enterprises receive additional differential profit (monopoly profit).

The state pursuing a policy of high customs duties acts here as an agent of monopoly associations. It is only thanks to the assistance of the state that the establishment of monopoly prices is conceivable. It is only thanks to the help of the state that the monopolist gangs are able to exploit the population of the country.

The monopoly profit received by the financial-capitalist groups is not only their goal, but, to a large extent, also a means of competition in the foreign market.

The monopoly profit received by the financial-capitalist groups is not only their goal, but, to a large extent, also a means of competition in the foreign market. Receiving huge premiums on the home market, the capitalist associations are able to export their goods abroad at significantly reduced prices. The internal premium makes it easier for them to compete with foreign rivals and often allows them to sell goods abroad at undoubtedly unprofitable prices.

“As an example, it suffices here to quote the history of the German sugar industry, which at the end of the 19th century exported about 3/5 of its production abroad. Since these exports were accompanied by large losses, the German sugar producers had to get high prices in the domestic markets.

When, therefore, in May 1900 they succeeded in creating a cartel covering 99.5% of the total sugar production in Germany, then immediately after this, prices in the home markets were immediately raised by 10%. The cartel, however, did not limit itself to this increase in its income; this is evident from the fact that while raw sugar was becoming cheaper and cheaper, the prices of refined sugar were kept at such a level that, with an artificial increase in them by 16-18 marks per 100 kilograms, German consumers had to annually overpay the sugar syndicate a huge amount of 100 million marks. An even more striking picture is in Russia's pre-war sugar industry. The famous Russian sugar syndicate achieved, with obvious support from the government, a complete monopoly in the domestic market.

Importation of sugar from abroad was completely stopped by high customs duties. This made it possible for the sugar syndicate to sell sugar domestically at 11-13 kopecks per pound (in retail trade), while production costs barely reached 5-6 kopecks.  Inside the country, the syndicate thus earned up to 7 kopecks (more than 100 percent) on each pound of sugar. At the same time, on the world market, he faced fierce competition from Austro-German and especially English factories.

In order to bankrupt their main competitor, the syndicate sold Russian sugar to England at 8 kopecks per pound, which allowed English farmers to feed their pigs with Russian sugar, while the Russian peasant drank tea as a " «priglyadku» (Russian proverb=without adding sugar, but only looking at sugar)

(Add Page 56 without Stats)

Much more important is the question of the distribution of these reserves among the individual capitalist countries. It is known that lowering market prices is by no means the only method of competitive struggle. Along with it, a prominent place is occupied by the deprivation of the enemy of raw materials. Each of the capitalists strives not only to provide himself with raw materials, but also to keep his competitor out of the raw materials. Therefore, each of the monopoly groups participating in world competition strives to seize not only those raw materials that are necessary for its own needs, but also those that its opponent needs or may need.

That is why all deposits of oil, coal and all kinds of ores serve as objects of fierce struggle between the largest capitalist groups and the states merged with them. In these points of the globe, the appetites of all the major powers are cracked. These places turn out to be the nodes of the imperialist struggle.

It is known that one of the main reasons for the last imperialist war was the desire of the “ally” to deprive Germany of coal (the Saar and Ruhr basins, Upper Silesia) and iron (Alsace-Lorraine) and thereby undermine her economic might; and, on the other hand, Germany's desire to take possession of the French iron ore basin (Brieet department).

It is no less known that almost all major European conflicts that have arisen in recent years and threatened Europe with new military upheavals arose on the same coal-and-iron base (the Ruhr conflict, the Polish-German conflict, the Czech-Polish friction).

A significant role in the World War was also played by the striving of the largest imperialist predators towards the oil basins: Germany towards Mesopotamia and Rumania, Great Britain towards Mesopotamia, and Persia.

The struggle for oil also played a significant role in the intervention of the "allies" in the Caucasus, and Japan in Kamchatka and Sakhalin in the development of the Greco-Turkish conflict, where England stood behind Greece, striving for Mossul, and Turkey was partially supported by France and the United States. States that did not want to let England into this rich oil basin.

The oil issue promises to remain the axis of international relations in the coming decades. The largest oil-consuming country, the United States (its consumption is about 70% of the world), is close to the complete exhaustion of its sources.

If The States will not want to become dependent on England, which has seized control of most of the world's oil reserves, they will have to make an attempt in the next few years to expand their oil possessions. And since England is unlikely to want to voluntarily release the enemy from the noose thrown around his neck, clashes over the oil issue seem inevitable.

Countries such as Mexico, Peru, Bolivia, Persia, and Mesopotamia will have to serve as subjects of fierce struggle in the coming years. However, along with minerals, raw materials supplied by agriculture are also the subject of fierce struggle. This branch of production in capitalist society, for reasons which we cannot dwell on here (reasons connected with the phenomena of rent), constantly lags behind the manufacturing industry in its development.

In capitalist society, therefore, there is a chronic shortage of agricultural products (bread, flax, cotton, and all kinds of foodstuffs). The prices for these products are constantly rising. However, this price increase cannot repulse consumers since they absolutely cannot do without these items. Because of the possibility of obtaining raw materials for industry in the required quantity, a fierce struggle flare up.

Each of the competing adversaries seeks to secure for itself a sufficient number of sources of raw materials for monopoly use, to which the adversary would not have access.

To this end, the monopoly associations are pushing the states associated with them onto the path of capturing the agrarian countries.

Economic competition degenerates into competition for conquest. Each of the competing countries is feverishly seizing "everything that lies badly", all the lands that do not have a specific owner.

(Stats)

We see that every major power of modern times, striving to acquire a sufficient number of colonies, i.e. countries supplying raw materials for capitalist industry, is steadily increasing its "possessions". If two of the great powers: Russia and Germany have lost their colonial possessions, then the reason for this, of course, lies not in the absence of "evil will" among the imperialists of these countries, but in the revolution that turned the Russian Empire into a free union of peoples, on the one hand, and in the military defeat of Germany on the other.

No comments

Powered by Blogger.